|
发表于 2014-6-30 21:41:18
|
显示全部楼层
that produced a series of supply shocks.
The Current Economic Predicament
The signals that we're in for some heavy weather are gathering pace. For a generation old enough to remember, things look quite familiar. It seems we've been here before.
The Fed announced that it is unlikely that there will be further rate cuts. With inflation creeping up further and the economy on the brink of a recession (if not already in one), this is not a surprise, to beat inflation, rates need to go up,nike air max cheap, to get the economy going, rates need to go down.
This is an awkward dilemma. We haven't seen this kind of policy dilemma's since the 1970s. That decade also coined a word for it, stagflation. From the experience in that decade, we also know how to deal with it. And that ain't going to be a nice experience.
Stagflation in the 1970s caused general bewilderment for policymakers because,scarpe hogan outlet, as we just explained above, economic forces were pulling policy instruments in opposite directions. Traditional Keynesian theory could deal with inflation and it could deal with a recession, but not with both.
What actually happened in the 1970s was a so called 'supply shock' (or, better, a series of supply shocks). The previous decade of high growth had pushed unemployment to extremely low levels,nike air max 1, just at a time when the labour movement was radicalizing and gathering strength.
This also coincided with a slowdown in productivity growth,cheap air max 90, which was the most fundamental reason behind the economic problems of the 1970s. Why?
It's simple, really. If labour produces 3% more output a year (because of better machines, more efficient ways of working,cheap nike tn shoes, production process innovation, etc.), it can also earn 3% more a year without getting more expensive.
But the new realities were that labour productivity slowed down markedly in the early 1970s just when the climate was getting much more difficult for labour to moderate it's wage demands, which was really necessary. If productivity grows at 1%, but wages keep on rising at 3%, labour becomes more expensive by 2% a year.
This squeezes profit margins and sets off inflation as some companies can increase output prices to recoup the rising cost of their employees. Increasing output prices is, well, inflation. And this made wage demands increase further, setting in motion a wage price spiral.
The reasons behind that slowdown in productivity growth are still a bit of a mystery, but it's likely that the whole 'Fordist' paradigm of mass production had ran it's course, the low hanging fruit had been picked and the technology to shift towards a new production paradigm was still in it's infancy.
Then came another catalyst in the form of an oil shock (sounds familiar!). In fact, it was not only the price of oil going up, but also the prices of many commodities (that also sounds familiar!),hogan rebel uomo, and there was another shock, the explosion of the system of fixed exchange rates that was set in 1944 in Bretton Woods.
The abandonment of that system made it possible for the US dollar to fall significantly against other currencies, which it duly did (another familiarity), and OPEC, the organization of petroleum exporting countries wasn't too happy with this, as oil is priced in dollars.
The Yom Kipur war of 1973 gave them the perfect excuse to hike oil prices (and use it as a political weapon; the US and The Netherlands were singled out for a total oil boycot, prompting the legendary Dutch prime minister of the day to say to a bewildered nation that "things would never be the same again").
So, in summary, we had a couple of supply shocks (productivity slowdown, labour scarcity, commodities, the demise of the Bretton Woods system) and particular political circumstances (labour radicalization, the emergence of OPEC) that produced a series of supply shocks.
A supply shock is basically a one off increase in the prices of inputs that are used in most production processes. They create inflation (obviously), but also reduce economic growth and increase unemployment, hence the term stagflation.
Supply shocks were a rather new phenomenon for policy makers and freed from having to defend exchange rates because of the demise of the Bretton Woods system, there was a good deal of policy experimentation on how to deal with that. We can now learn from that experimentation.
Countries like Germany, Japan, Switzerland, The Netherlands gave priority to fighting inflation and embarked on sound money policies,?spaccio hogan marche, whilst other countries (the UK, Italy, France until 1977) made fighting unemployment their main task through reflationary demand stimulation (increasing public spending,air max 97, tax cuts, and the like).
The countries embarking on deflationary policies fared a lot better than others, which experienced runaway inflation as a result. In the UK, for instance, inflation reached 20%. And once inflation is out of the bottle, it's very difficult (and costly) to reign it in, as inflationary expectations become embedded in the minds of wage and price setters.
This is the main reason why those countries embarking on deflationary policies fared better, inflationary expectations did not get much chance to really establish themselves in those countries. The Bundesbank,nike tn 2014, (West) Germany's central bank became the paragon of these sound money policies.
It's hard to believe now, but in the US, a republican administration actually embarked on wage and price controls. Obviously, this was before the Reagan revolution which turned the belief in free market into something of a fetish.
Inflation was only quelled when the Fed under Volcker embarked on similar policies in 1979 as the German Bundesbank five years earlier, but the costs of those 5 years were high,nike air max 90 sale, interest rates had to rise into double digit territory, setting off the international debt crisis and a world wide recession in the process. Are those lessons actually applicable today? In order to answer that question we have to look whether the situations are really that comparable.
This time around, what are the differences and similarities? Now, there are also a series of supply shocks, we have a commodities boom and a sinking dollarUnlike the 1970s, there is no marked slowdown in productivity growth, and the power of organized labour to increase wages is much reduced (due to globalization and a decline in unions power)Inflation hasn't (yet?) reached the levels of the 1970sSo it might seem that we're better off, however, there are additional serious shocks to the system, the US housing market is in a deep slump, the end of which might not be in sight for some considerable time to come, and we have a very brittle financial system which is a drag on the system (as it's willingness to supply credit is not exactly rife at the moment). We think that the situation is likely to be worse today than in the 1970s. This is the result of a couple of opposing forces:
Better is that the inflationary dynamics are not nearly as strong as in the 1970s, as organized labour has lost it's strength, productivity growth has not been affected (so far, at least),borse hogan, so there is less chance of a wage price spiralHowever, the room for embarking on deflationary policies to quell inflation has also been reduced, and reduced quite significantly. If the Fed would increase interest rates,mens nike air max, the housing market would really crash, and the financial system could worsen furtherAnd monetary policy seems less powerful. The credit crisis has made banks and other financial institutions credit shy, lowering interest rates doesn't have the same punch as before. And there is one joker in the pack: Chinese inflation. If inflation in China (approaching double digit rates already) would really take off, one of the main deflationary forces in the world economy (cheap imports from China) would shift into reverse.
The Chinese economy is so open (international trade actually constitutes a much larger part of the economy compared to the US, Japan, or the European Union) that it is importing relatively more inflation from the commodities boom compared to these other regions.
The Chinese economy, meanwhile, has been surprisingly robust during this onslaught. One would expect the economy to cool off, thereby also soften the impact of the commodities boom on prices, but very little of that seems to have happened until now. Cooling the economy off too much could endanger world economic growth further (and it could even destabilize China itself). Unabated growth could cause inflation spiraling out of control (and would have much the same effect).
So, surprising as it may be, those lessons from the 1970s are useful in an unexpected part of the world: China. They should err on the side of caution. One way to do that would be something that is inevitable anyway, let the currency rise.相关的主题文章:
"El "Ruta in Ecuador and Ven
"the whole meaning of his for
Giant military cargo plane lands at small Tampa airport
information" said Dennis Eicher director for Electronic Commerce Military and Civilian Pay Services at DFAS "We are providing myPay customers access to their tax and pay preferences online We also know some individuals would rather have a hard copy statement so we are giving them that choice" The online version complete with printing instructions is 100 percent compatible for all tax |
|